Power Structure Dynamics in Growing Multilateral Development Banks: The Case of the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank

Power Structure Dynamics in Growing Multilateral Development Banks: The Case of the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank

As the first multilateral development bank (MDB) initiated by China, the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB) has been growing rapidly, and within three years of its establishment, has become the second largest multilateral development bank after the World Bank. With the assistance of the supercomputer (Weiming‐1) and combing the method of generating functions, we measured precisely the voting power of each member of the AIIB (analysis which has been done for the first time for an organization with more than 80 members and more than 1 million distributed votes). We find that a host of member countries other than China have outsized power to prevent action on significant matters, but their power to initiate action are quite modest and closely distributed. Furthermore, the power structures in the AIIB are relatively even or ‘democratic’ on substantive matters when compared to procedural matters. More interestingly, we analyzed the dynamics of voting power of major members like China, India, Russia, Germany, the UK and France with the admission of new members. While the voting weights of all existing members decreased monotonously and proportionally, the voting power of some members in some cases even increased. We find that the requirements of voting rules, and the size of new and existing members, all affect how members’ power evolve. Lastly, we measured the balance of power and the decision‐making efficiency of the AIIB as a whole organization beyond individual members and discussed relationships between them. Our analysis aims to provide insights into the allocation of voting weights, the design of voting rules and importantly, the choice of membership expansions for growing multilateral development banks.

Policy Implications

  • In order to improve its decision‐making efficiency, the AIIB should adopt a less strict voting rule. Suffice it to say, higher decision‐making efficiency is accompanied by lower balance of power. Typically, there is a trade‐off between these two outcomes.
  • China can benefit from enlisting a greater proportion of issues to be voted by a simple majority rule instead of the Special Majority rule or the Super Majority rule since China’s voting power is much more prominent under a less strict voting rule.
  • With the expansion of the AIIB’s membership, the decrease of existing member countries’ voting weights is inevitable, but their voting power may in fact increase, depending on the attributes of new and existing member countries.
  • Countries hesitant to join the AIIB would be well‐served to join as the power structure of the AIIB is more even and balanced than expected.

 

Photo by Francesco Ungaro from Pexels